Public goods: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 24: Line 24:
The concept is often interpreted  to mean  that non-rivalous and non-excludable products and services can only supplied by governments. That interpretation was challenged by Ronald Coase, who pointed out that English lighthouses had been privately supplied and financed in the 19th century<ref> Ronald Coase 1974. ''The Lighthouse in Economics'', Journal of Law and Economics, 17, no. 2, 1974</ref>. The broader interpretation adopted in this article follows Samuelson in  stipulating  only that they cannot be paid for by individual users  - implying that, unlike private goods, their supply cannot respond to the normal action of market forces. But it does not exclude  the possibility that they could be collectively financed by the private sector. It is widely assumed that the scope for the private sector financing of public goods must be  limited by  the opportunities it affords for "free-riding", but  Elinor Ostrom has demonstrated ways in which that obstacle can be overcome<ref>[http://www.apsanet.org/media/PDFs/PresidentialAddresses/1997AddrOSTROM.pdf Elinor Ostrom: ''A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action'', Presidential Address to the American Political Science Association, 1997, American Political Science Association, Vol 92, No 1, 1998]</ref>. Public goods that are financed by the private sector are not in fact uncommon. Citizendium, for example,  is non-rivalous and  constitutionally non-excludable, and  is thus a public good although it is financed  by voluntary contributions from its supporters. It is neverthless true that most public goods are government-financed, and in popular usage the term is often applied to government-financed products such as  those roads and bridges to which access is not restricted - although such usage is not consistent with the non-excludability criterion, nor with the fact that toll roads and bridges can be provided and financed by the private sector. Since, however, the distinction between public goods and the broader category of collective  goods depends upon the technical possibility of exclusion, it can be blurred by doubts concerning methods of exclusion that are possible but not available - or possible but not commercially feasible. Whether the global positioning system  should be categorised as a public good, for example, turns upon the feasibility of coded access.  
The concept is often interpreted  to mean  that non-rivalous and non-excludable products and services can only supplied by governments. That interpretation was challenged by Ronald Coase, who pointed out that English lighthouses had been privately supplied and financed in the 19th century<ref> Ronald Coase 1974. ''The Lighthouse in Economics'', Journal of Law and Economics, 17, no. 2, 1974</ref>. The broader interpretation adopted in this article follows Samuelson in  stipulating  only that they cannot be paid for by individual users  - implying that, unlike private goods, their supply cannot respond to the normal action of market forces. But it does not exclude  the possibility that they could be collectively financed by the private sector. It is widely assumed that the scope for the private sector financing of public goods must be  limited by  the opportunities it affords for "free-riding", but  Elinor Ostrom has demonstrated ways in which that obstacle can be overcome<ref>[http://www.apsanet.org/media/PDFs/PresidentialAddresses/1997AddrOSTROM.pdf Elinor Ostrom: ''A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action'', Presidential Address to the American Political Science Association, 1997, American Political Science Association, Vol 92, No 1, 1998]</ref>. Public goods that are financed by the private sector are not in fact uncommon. Citizendium, for example,  is non-rivalous and  constitutionally non-excludable, and  is thus a public good although it is financed  by voluntary contributions from its supporters. It is neverthless true that most public goods are government-financed, and in popular usage the term is often applied to government-financed products such as  those roads and bridges to which access is not restricted - although such usage is not consistent with the non-excludability criterion, nor with the fact that toll roads and bridges can be provided and financed by the private sector. Since, however, the distinction between public goods and the broader category of collective  goods depends upon the technical possibility of exclusion, it can be blurred by doubts concerning methods of exclusion that are possible but not available - or possible but not commercially feasible. Whether the global positioning system  should be categorised as a public good, for example, turns upon the feasibility of coded access.  


Some writers consider  government-financed products and services to have  private goods components if they confer particular benefits upon one section of the community (the  patent system, for example, has been held to have a private goods component because it confers additional  benefits on inventors. Products and services need  not benefit everyone equally  for them to be defined as public goods but, even if  they are non-exclusive,  they  may seem to be akin to a transfer payment or a subsidy rather than a public good if they benefit only by a segment of the community,
Some writers consider  government-financed products and services to have  private goods components if they confer particular benefits upon one section of the community (the  patent system, for example, has been held to have a private goods component because it confers additional  benefits on inventors. Products and services need  not benefit everyone equally  for them to be defined as public goods but, even if  they are non-exclusive,  they  may seem to be akin to a transfer payment or a subsidy rather than a public good if they benefit only a segment of the community,


==References==
==References==
<references/>
<references/>

Revision as of 13:02, 28 October 2009

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Public goods are products and services that can only be collectively financed because it is not feasible to require individual users to pay for using them.

The origins of the concept

In the 18th century, Adam Smith wrote:

"The third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth is that of erecting or maintaining those public institutions and those public works, which, although they may be in the highest degree advantageous to a great society, are, however, of such a nature, that the profit could not repay the expense to any individual or small number of individuals, and which it therefore cannot be expected that any individual or small number of individuals should erect or maintain ."[1];

- in the 19th century, John Stuart Mill elaborated the idea, arguing as an example that it would be impossible to charge seamen according to their use of lighthouses

it is a proper office of government to build and maintain lighthouses, establish buoys, &c. for the security of navigation: for since it is impossible that the ships at sea which are benefited by a lighthouse, should be made to pay a toll on the occasion of its use, no one would build lighthouses from motives of personal interest, unless indemnified and rewarded from a compulsory levy made by the state. [2];

- and in the 20th century, Paul Samuelson (who at first referred to public goods as "collective consumption goods") derived a formal proof of the proposition that "no decentralized pricing system can serve to determine optimally the levels of collective consumption" [3]

Defining characteristics

Pure public goods are held to be:

  • non-rivalous, meaning that anyone can benefit from them without diminishing their benefits to other people;
  • non-excludable, meaning that no-one can be prevented from benefiting from them;

- and they are often:

  • non-rejectable, meaning that nobody can avoid benefiting from them.

The term "club goods" is applied to products and services that are non-rivalous, but from which "non-members" are excluded.

The term "collective goods" is sometimes used to denote the broader category of products and services, including both private goods and public goods, that are collectively financed.

Rival interpretations

The concept is often interpreted to mean that non-rivalous and non-excludable products and services can only supplied by governments. That interpretation was challenged by Ronald Coase, who pointed out that English lighthouses had been privately supplied and financed in the 19th century[4]. The broader interpretation adopted in this article follows Samuelson in stipulating only that they cannot be paid for by individual users - implying that, unlike private goods, their supply cannot respond to the normal action of market forces. But it does not exclude the possibility that they could be collectively financed by the private sector. It is widely assumed that the scope for the private sector financing of public goods must be limited by the opportunities it affords for "free-riding", but Elinor Ostrom has demonstrated ways in which that obstacle can be overcome[5]. Public goods that are financed by the private sector are not in fact uncommon. Citizendium, for example, is non-rivalous and constitutionally non-excludable, and is thus a public good although it is financed by voluntary contributions from its supporters. It is neverthless true that most public goods are government-financed, and in popular usage the term is often applied to government-financed products such as those roads and bridges to which access is not restricted - although such usage is not consistent with the non-excludability criterion, nor with the fact that toll roads and bridges can be provided and financed by the private sector. Since, however, the distinction between public goods and the broader category of collective goods depends upon the technical possibility of exclusion, it can be blurred by doubts concerning methods of exclusion that are possible but not available - or possible but not commercially feasible. Whether the global positioning system should be categorised as a public good, for example, turns upon the feasibility of coded access.

Some writers consider government-financed products and services to have private goods components if they confer particular benefits upon one section of the community (the patent system, for example, has been held to have a private goods component because it confers additional benefits on inventors. Products and services need not benefit everyone equally for them to be defined as public goods but, even if they are non-exclusive, they may seem to be akin to a transfer payment or a subsidy rather than a public good if they benefit only a segment of the community,

References