Public goods: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
No edit summary
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 6: Line 6:
In the 18th century, Adam Smith wrote:   
In the 18th century, Adam Smith wrote:   
:"The third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth is that of erecting or maintaining those public institutions and those public works, which, although they may be in the highest degree advantageous to a great society, are, however, of such a nature, that the profit could not repay the expense to any individual or small number of individuals, and which it therefore cannot be expected that any individual or small number of individuals should erect or maintain ."<ref>[http://www.adamsmith.org/smith/won-b5-c1-pt-3.htm Adam Smith: ''An Inquiry into the Nature And Causes of the Wealth of Nations'', Book 5, Chapter 1, Part 3, (first published 1776)]</ref>;<br>  
:"The third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth is that of erecting or maintaining those public institutions and those public works, which, although they may be in the highest degree advantageous to a great society, are, however, of such a nature, that the profit could not repay the expense to any individual or small number of individuals, and which it therefore cannot be expected that any individual or small number of individuals should erect or maintain ."<ref>[http://www.adamsmith.org/smith/won-b5-c1-pt-3.htm Adam Smith: ''An Inquiry into the Nature And Causes of the Wealth of Nations'', Book 5, Chapter 1, Part 3, (first published 1776)]</ref>;<br>  
-  in the 19th century, John Stuart Mill elaborated the idea, using lighthouses as an example, arguing it would be impossible to try to charge seamen according to their use or benefit from the lighthouse<ref>[http://www.econlib.org/library/Mill/mlP.html John Stuart Mill: ''Principles of Political Economy'', Book 5, Chapter 10, Longmans, Green, 1848]</ref>;<br>
-  in the 19th century, John Stuart Mill elaborated the idea, arguing  as an example that it would be impossible to charge seamen according to their use of lighthouses<ref>[http://www.econlib.org/library/Mill/mlP.html John Stuart Mill: ''Principles of Political Economy'', Book 5, Chapter 10, Longmans, Green, 1848]</ref>;<br>
- and in the 20th century, Paul Samuelson (who referred to public goods as  "collective consumption goods") derived a formal proof of the proposition that "no decentralized pricing system can serve to determine optimally the levels of collective consumption" <ref> Paul Samuelson: ''The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure'', Review of Economics and Statistics, vol 36 1954</ref><br>
- and in the 20th century, Paul Samuelson (who referred to public goods as  "collective consumption goods") derived a formal proof of the proposition that "no decentralized pricing system can serve to determine optimally the levels of collective consumption" <ref> Paul Samuelson: ''The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure'', Review of Economics and Statistics, vol 36 1954</ref><br>


''Possible qualifications to the above are discussed below''  
''Possible qualifications to the above are discussed below''
 
 


==The formal definition==
==The formal definition==

Revision as of 10:07, 26 October 2009

This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Public goods are products and services, such as lighthouses and national defence, that can only be financed by governments, because it is not possible to devise a pricing system to enable them to be marketed.

The origins of the concept

In the 18th century, Adam Smith wrote:

"The third and last duty of the sovereign or commonwealth is that of erecting or maintaining those public institutions and those public works, which, although they may be in the highest degree advantageous to a great society, are, however, of such a nature, that the profit could not repay the expense to any individual or small number of individuals, and which it therefore cannot be expected that any individual or small number of individuals should erect or maintain ."[1];

- in the 19th century, John Stuart Mill elaborated the idea, arguing as an example that it would be impossible to charge seamen according to their use of lighthouses[2];
- and in the 20th century, Paul Samuelson (who referred to public goods as "collective consumption goods") derived a formal proof of the proposition that "no decentralized pricing system can serve to determine optimally the levels of collective consumption" [3]

Possible qualifications to the above are discussed below

The formal definition

Partly public goods

References