Eurozone crisis/Tutorials

From Citizendium
< Eurozone crisis
Revision as of 08:22, 6 December 2011 by imported>Nick Gardner (→‎Conditional loans)
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Catalogs [?]
Timelines [?]
Tutorials [?]
Addendum [?]
 
Tutorials relating to the topic of Eurozone crisis.

Departures from optimum currency area criteria

Currency area theory is concerned with extent to which efficiency gains from currency area membership are offset by losses due to increased vulnerability to external economic shocks, and the term "optimum currency area" (OCA) denotes an area in which such offsets are absent. Although an idealistic concept, it has practical implications because the increased costs of recessions, brought about by increased vulnerability to shocks, can be large compared with the benefits of the efficiency gains. For that reason it is generally accepted that a currency area may not succeed unless it goes a substantial way toward meeting OCA criteria. A currency area fully meets OCA criteria if there is complete price flexibility, or complete cross-boarder mobility of labour and capital. An alternative requirement arises from the fact that increased vulnerability to shocks need not occur if every shock has the same impact on all the economies of the member states. The term "convergence" is sometimes used to denote a condition in which the economies of members states are so similar as to eliminate asymmetric shocks - or to denote an approach to that condition.

The eurozone has not satisfied the OCA labour migration or price flexibility conditions. Labour mobility is low[1] and there is only limited wage and price flexibility[2][3]. Nor has it satisfied the convergence condition. There has been less price convergence among eurozone countries than among European Union countries as a whole,[4], and there have been large divergences of productivity, unit labour costs, and current account balances. The progress toward convergence as a result of membership, that was expected by the early proponents of monetary union[5], has not occurred.

The debt trap

If the annual interest payable on a government's debt were to continue to rise faster than the national income, it would eventually exceed the feasible revenue from taxation. The process is normally hastened by the fact that government debt is traded in a well-informed market. Operators in that market would be aware of the approach of the point at which the government would be forced to default on its debt, and they would be increasingly reluctant to allow that government to continue to roll over its debt. The government concerned could seek to overcome that reluctance by offering them higher interest on future loans, but an increase in the interest to be paid would hasten the process and increase the reluctance of further potential investors. That is what is known as the debt trap, the price formulation of which is the the debt trap identity.

The debt trap could be escaped:

- (i) by repudiation of the debt;
- (ii) (temporarily) by a negotiation with creditors to ease the terms of repayment (termed restructuring);
- (iii) (temporarily) by getting the country's central bank to purchase the debt; or,
- (iv) by a programme of reductions in public expenditure and/or increases in rates of taxation.

Options (i) and (ii) have the drawback of making future investors reluctant to buy the government's bonds. Option (iii) can also have that effect if it causes an inflation that reduces the value of the currency in which the debt is to be repaid. Option (iv) is free from that drawback, but is effective only if it avoids creating a recession that increases the deficit (by the operation of the country's automatic stabilisers).

Fewer options are available to members of a currency union, however. Option (iii) may be excluded by the fact that monetary policy is no longer under the control of the borrowing government. That fact also prevents the use of monetary policy to counter the recessionary consequences of (iv), (without which that option may be ineffective); and the rules of the currency union prevent the exchange rate deprecation that might otherwise counter them. To make (iii) possible and (iv) easier, a further option would be (v) - to leave the currency union.

Policy options

Conditional loans

The EU/IMF loans had been primarily intended to restore the confidence of the bond markets in their recipients' ability to meet their financial obligations and give the recipient governments time in which to restore their fiscal sustainability, and have been conditional upon the adoption of stringent fiscal adjustments. Since May 2010, the EU components of such loans have been supplied by the European Financial Stability Facility subject to the approval of the parliaments of the eurozone countries. Proposals to refinance the Facility by using the Europan Central Bank[6] have not been adopted and, as it stands, it is too small for rescues of the larger eurozne countries such as Spain and Italy.

Bond guarantees

As one means of "leveraging" the European Financial Stability Facility, it has been proposed that it should offer partial guarantees against loss by a purchaser of a member government's bonds, for example by assuming a portion ofthe loss amounting to a stated percentage of the issue value of the bond.

Co-investment funds

Another form of leverage is the creation of a co-investment fund to enable the deployment of a combination of European Financial Stability Facility and private sector resources.

Bond purchases

Before May 2010, the European Central Bank had used bond purchases only for the purpose of monetary policy[7], but in May 2010, in a major policy change, it decided to buy European government bonds[8] in order to assist governments who were experiencing funding difficulties - a policy change that was opposed by Axel Weber, the then President of the German central bank[9]. Purchases are reported to have included the bonds of all of the PIIGS countries, including Spain and Italy.

The ECB as lender of last resort to member states

It has been proposed that, instead of the provision of loans at the case-by-case discretion of member countries, the duty should be placed upon the European Central Bank to provide assistance to member governments when it is needed, raising the necessary funds by monetisation. The proposal has been rejected on the grounds of fear of moral hazard and of the possible creation of inflation as a result of the consequent increase in the money supply.

Eurobonds

In December 2010, two Eurogroup finance ministers put forward a proposal under which bonds issued by individual governments would be collectively guaranteed by the other eurozone governments, [10]. In August 2011, the financier George Soros argued that eurobonds would have to be an essential feature of any effective Greek rescue package[11], an assessment that was endorsed by the eminent economist, Joseph Stiglitz [12]. Among variants on the concept are the "Blue Bond" proposal, under which eurozone governments would pool up to 60 percent of GDP of their government debt in the form of a common European government bond [13], and its "partial sovereign bond insurance" alternative [14].

In November 2011, the European Commission published an analysis[15] of the pros and cons of three alternative of eurobonds (which they dubbed "stability bonds"):

(a )the full substitution by stability bond issuance of national issuance, with joint and several guarantees:
(b) the partial substitution by stability bond issuance of national issuance, with joint and several guarantees: or,
(c) the partial substitution by stability bond issuance of national issuance, with several but not joint guarantees:

Fiscal integration

It has been argued by the economist Wolfgang Münchau, and others, that the eurozone embodies a logical inconsistency that will continue to make it vulnerable to economic shocks unless it is resolved by the introduction of some form of fiscal union[16]. There have been a number of proposals that would serve the purpose without the imposition of a common budget. The European Commission has proposed eurozone countries should be required to present their draft budgets at the same time each year, so that the Commission could then issue an opinion on them, and ask governments to revise them if necessary[17]. Another Commission proposal would require governments that are threatened with financial difficulties to submit to close budgetary surveillance by the Commission [18]. It has been suggested that, in view of the failure of existing means of enforcement, national budgets should be submitted to the European Court of Justice for validation of their compliance with federal law - so that an invalidated national budget would be illegal[19].

Restructuring of debt

It is generally accepted that the costs of sovereign default to all concerned are such as to make its avoidance a high priority objective. But it has been argued that, when default becomes unavoidable, some of those costs can be avoided by a timely "restructuring" agreement with the country's creditors. In May 2011, European Finance Ministers discussed the possibility of a rescheduling of the Greek government's debt (also referred to as "soft restructuring" or "reprofiling")[20]', and a reduction by half of Greece's debt, was subsequently adopted as one of the decisions of October 2011.

Bank recapitalisation

European banks had already suffered reductions in their assets as a result of falls in the value of their holdings of Greek bonds, and a resulting reductions in their capital adequacy ratios had resulted in their failure to pass stress tests [21]. Further large-scale recapitalisation, was considered in October 2011 to be a necessary adjunct to the restructuring of the Greek government's debts without which it would result in multiple bank failures.

Internal devaluation

Since it is not open to eurozone governments to increase the international competitiveness of their countries' products by devaluation, some have sought to do so by measures to reduce the costs of production, for example by reducing the tax wedge that raises the cost of labour to employers above the take-home pay of employees. The same objective may be served by the downward pressure on wage rates brought about by increases in unemployment resulting from fiscal adjustments designed to restore sustainability.

Exit from the eurozone

Departure from the eurozone would enable a country to monetise its debt, and would offer the prospect of an increase in competetiveness resulting from a currency devaluation. However, according to a study by UBS economists, the benefits to a country like Greece would be overwhelmingly outweighed by costs. It would also result in mass sovereign and corporate default, a major increase in the cost of capital, and the collapse of its banking system[22] (the first-year cost of its departure was later estimated to be 40 to 50 per cent of GDP. [23]). The economic commentator, Anotole Kaletsky, has argued that the "seemingly impossible" solution of a German exit might become inevitable, and would be much less disruptive than a Greek expulsion because it would not trigger bank runs in countries, but would enable a devalued euro to be managed on less austere principles[24]. But the UBS economists estimate that departure of Germany would lead to a first-year loss to its economy of 20 to 25 per cent of GDP.

References

  1. Alexandre Janiak and Etienne Wasmer: Mobility in Europe, European Commission, 2008
  2. Alfonso Arpaia and Karl Pichelmann: Nominal and real wage flexibility in EMU, European Commission, 2007
  3. Emmanuel Dhyne, Jerzy Konieczny, Fabio Rumler and Patrick Sevestre: Price Rigidity in the Euro Area, European Commission, 2009
  4. Clas Wihjborg.Thomas Willett and NanZhang: The Euro Debt Crisis. It isn't just fiscal, World Economics, October-December 2010 (figures 3-6)
  5. One market, one money. An evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming an economic and monetary union, European Economy, No 44 October 1990
  6. Daniel Gros and Thomas Mayer: Refinancing the EFSF via the ECB, CEPS 18 August 2011
  7. Decision of the Governors of the European Central Bank of 2 July 2009 on the implementation of the covered bond purchase programme, (ECB/2009/16) European Central Bank
  8. ECB decides on measures to address severe tensions in financial markets European Central Bank, 10 May 2010
  9. [http://www.centralbanking.com/central-banking/news/1635917/cracks-emerge-ecb-s-bond-purchases Ramya Jaidev: Cracks emerge over ECB’s bond purchases, Central Banking, 11 May 2010]
  10. Jean-Claude Juncker and Giulio Tremonti: E-bonds would end the crisis, Financial Times, December 5 2010
  11. "You Need This Dirty Word, Euro Bonds", Interview with George Soros, Spiegel Online, 15 August 2011
  12. Difficult for euro to survive without eurobonds:Stiglitz, Reuters,16 August 2011
  13. Jacques Delpla and Jakob von Weizsäcker: The Blue Bond Proposal, bruegelpolicybrief, Bruegel Institute, May 2010
  14. Hans-Joachim Dübel: Partial sovereign bond insurance by the eurozone: A more efficient alternative to blue (Euro-)bonds, CEPS Policy Brief No. 252, August 2011
  15. Green Paper on the feasibility of introducing Stability Bonds, European Comission, 23 November 2011
  16. Wolfgang Münchau: Fiscal union is crucial to the euro’s survival, Financial Times, November 14 2010
  17. Proposal for a regulation on common provisions for monitoring and assessing draft budgetary plans and ensuring the correction of excessive deficit of the Member States in the euro area, European Commission, 23 November 2011
  18. [http://ec.europa.eu/commission_2010-2014/president/news/documents/pdf/regulation_2_en.pdf Proposal for a regulation on on the strengthening of economic and budgetary surveillance of Member States experiencing or threatened with serious difficulties with respect to their financial stability in the euro area, European Commission, 23 November 2011]
  19. The fiscal solution, Buttonwood's Notebook, The Economist, Nov 29th 2011
  20. EU breaks taboo, talks of Greek debt restructuring, Reuters, May 17, 2011
  21. Eight banks fail EU stress test with 16 in danger zone, BBC News, 15 July 2011
  22. Stephane Deo, Paul Donovan Sophie Constable and Larry Hatheway: How to break up a monetary union, Global Economic Perspectives, UBS Investment Research[www.ubs.com/economics], February 2011]
  23. Sam Fleming: Devastating price of euro failure, Times, 7 September 2011
  24. Anatole Kaletsky: A euro without Germany? Don’t bet against it, The Times, 14 September 2011