Welfare economics: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
{{subpages}}
{{subpages}}
The concept of welfare is concerned with the  well-being of the individual, and the subject matter of '''welfare economics''' is the influence of collective decisions upon the  welfare of groups of individuals. The theorems of welfare economics constitute the rationale for the criteria of [[economic efficiency]],  the theoretical benefits of market [[competition]], and the practice of [[cost-benefit analysis]].
The concept of welfare is concerned with the  well-being of the individual, and the subject matter of '''welfare economics''' is the influence of collective decisions upon the  welfare of groups of individuals. The theorems of welfare economics provide the theoretical basis for the benefits of market [[competition]], the practice of [[cost-benefit analysis]] and many other aspects of economic theory.


===Definition===
===Definition===
Line 8: Line 8:
The aggregate increase in welfare resulting from an action cannot be quantified because interpersonal comparisons of welfare are conceptually impossible. However, it is possible to determine whether an activity increases or  decreases an individual's economic welfare. One way of overcoming the conceptual barrier is to deem that an activity will increase efficiency only if it makes somebody better off without making anybody worse off. Efficiency so defined is termed ''Pareto efficiency'' in honour of the economist, Vilfredo Pareto, who first put that definition  forward.  In a somewhat different sense, the terms ''Pareto efficient'' and ''Pareto optimum '' are  used to describe an ideal state of affairs from which it is impossible to make a change which would make anybody better off without making somebody else worse off. The Pareto criterion is too restrictive to be generally useful, so for practical purposes it is normally replaced by the criterion that efficiency is deemed to  be increased if those who gain as the result of an action would benefit from it after compensating those who lose from it.  This is the criterion that is used in cost/benefit analysis, but its application is strictly valid only if the compensation is actually paid. This is sometimes referred to as the ''compensation principle''
The aggregate increase in welfare resulting from an action cannot be quantified because interpersonal comparisons of welfare are conceptually impossible. However, it is possible to determine whether an activity increases or  decreases an individual's economic welfare. One way of overcoming the conceptual barrier is to deem that an activity will increase efficiency only if it makes somebody better off without making anybody worse off. Efficiency so defined is termed ''Pareto efficiency'' in honour of the economist, Vilfredo Pareto, who first put that definition  forward.  In a somewhat different sense, the terms ''Pareto efficient'' and ''Pareto optimum '' are  used to describe an ideal state of affairs from which it is impossible to make a change which would make anybody better off without making somebody else worse off. The Pareto criterion is too restrictive to be generally useful, so for practical purposes it is normally replaced by the criterion that efficiency is deemed to  be increased if those who gain as the result of an action would benefit from it after compensating those who lose from it.  This is the criterion that is used in cost/benefit analysis, but its application is strictly valid only if the compensation is actually paid. This is sometimes referred to as the ''compensation principle''


===Fundamental theorems of welfare economics===
==The benefits of competition==
In a market mechanism with flexible prices, individuals will continue to trade with each other until they reach an optimal outcome. The market provides a mechanism for individuals to communicate their preferences through prices so that each individual will be able to an optimal bundle of consumption given a particular budget constraint.  
In a market mechanism with flexible prices, individuals will continue to trade with each other until they reach an optimal outcome. The market provides a mechanism for individuals to communicate their preferences through prices so that each individual will be able to an optimal bundle of consumption given a particular budget constraint.  


====First theorem of Welfare Economics====
====The first theorem of welfare economics====
In a market with many traders where prices are flexible, any equilibrium will be pareto-optimal.  
In a market with many traders where prices are flexible, any equilibrium will be Pareto-optimal.  


====Second theorem of Welfare Economics====
====The second theorem of welfare economics====
Every outcome that is pareto-optimal can be realized in a market with many traders and flexible prices provided an appropriate initial distribution of endowments.
Every outcome that is Pareto-optimal can be realized in a market with many traders and flexible prices provided an appropriate initial distribution of endowments.
 
==Cost-benefit analysis==
 
==Other applications==


==References==
==References==
<references/>
<references/>

Revision as of 03:08, 11 April 2008

This article is developing and not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.

The concept of welfare is concerned with the well-being of the individual, and the subject matter of welfare economics is the influence of collective decisions upon the welfare of groups of individuals. The theorems of welfare economics provide the theoretical basis for the benefits of market competition, the practice of cost-benefit analysis and many other aspects of economic theory.

Definition

The definition of the welfare of an individual is the same as the definition of utility that is presented in the article on that subject, but the problem of defining collective or "social" welfare is greatly complicated by the logical impossibility, noted in that article, of making inter-personal comparisons of utility. The nature of that problem is discussed on the tutorials subpage, where it is noted that no completely satisfactory theoretical solution is available. Applied welfare economics consequently provides only partial ad-hoc solutions, qualified by the need to embody value judgments without totally abandoning the presumption that every individual is the sole judge of his own welfare. In many cases, however, the judgments required are so widely accepted as to present no practical difficulty. There is general acceptance, for example, that gains in individual welfare arising from psychotic satisfactions are not admissible components of social welfare.

The Pareto criterion

The aggregate increase in welfare resulting from an action cannot be quantified because interpersonal comparisons of welfare are conceptually impossible. However, it is possible to determine whether an activity increases or decreases an individual's economic welfare. One way of overcoming the conceptual barrier is to deem that an activity will increase efficiency only if it makes somebody better off without making anybody worse off. Efficiency so defined is termed Pareto efficiency in honour of the economist, Vilfredo Pareto, who first put that definition forward. In a somewhat different sense, the terms Pareto efficient and Pareto optimum are used to describe an ideal state of affairs from which it is impossible to make a change which would make anybody better off without making somebody else worse off. The Pareto criterion is too restrictive to be generally useful, so for practical purposes it is normally replaced by the criterion that efficiency is deemed to be increased if those who gain as the result of an action would benefit from it after compensating those who lose from it. This is the criterion that is used in cost/benefit analysis, but its application is strictly valid only if the compensation is actually paid. This is sometimes referred to as the compensation principle

The benefits of competition

In a market mechanism with flexible prices, individuals will continue to trade with each other until they reach an optimal outcome. The market provides a mechanism for individuals to communicate their preferences through prices so that each individual will be able to an optimal bundle of consumption given a particular budget constraint.

The first theorem of welfare economics

In a market with many traders where prices are flexible, any equilibrium will be Pareto-optimal.

The second theorem of welfare economics

Every outcome that is Pareto-optimal can be realized in a market with many traders and flexible prices provided an appropriate initial distribution of endowments.

Cost-benefit analysis

Other applications

References