Discount rate: Difference between revisions

From Citizendium
Jump to navigation Jump to search
imported>Nick Gardner
imported>Nick Gardner
Line 4: Line 4:
The concept of discounting arises from the behavioural observation  that people prefer  immediate satisfaction to deferred satisfaction.  Thus the term “discount rate” refers to the  compensation in terms of increased utility that a person requires as inducement to defer  consumption  (usually as a percentage per annum).  The discount rate that a person  experiences assuming no expectation of changing circumstances,  is sometimes termed his  “pure time preference rate”  - to distinguish it from the inducement that he would require if he  expected his consumption  to increase.  In that case,  he would take account of  the fact that, as his  total consumption increased,  he would experience  a reduction in the marginal utility of  any further increase <ref>See the article on [[supply and demand]]</ref>.  The proportionate further compensation  that a person requires to take account of its diminishing marginal utility is referred to as that person’s  “elasticity of the marginal utility of consumption”.  (The derivation of that concept is attributed to a 1928 paper by the economist [[Frank Ramsey]] <ref> Frank Ramsey “A Mathematical Theory of Saving”  Economic Journal Vol. 38 1928</ref>.  There is a note on the “Ramsey equation”, and the estimation of the associated elasticity measure, on the tutorials subpage.).  A community’s discount rate, taking  account of rising consumption, is termed its “social time preference rate”.
The concept of discounting arises from the behavioural observation  that people prefer  immediate satisfaction to deferred satisfaction.  Thus the term “discount rate” refers to the  compensation in terms of increased utility that a person requires as inducement to defer  consumption  (usually as a percentage per annum).  The discount rate that a person  experiences assuming no expectation of changing circumstances,  is sometimes termed his  “pure time preference rate”  - to distinguish it from the inducement that he would require if he  expected his consumption  to increase.  In that case,  he would take account of  the fact that, as his  total consumption increased,  he would experience  a reduction in the marginal utility of  any further increase <ref>See the article on [[supply and demand]]</ref>.  The proportionate further compensation  that a person requires to take account of its diminishing marginal utility is referred to as that person’s  “elasticity of the marginal utility of consumption”.  (The derivation of that concept is attributed to a 1928 paper by the economist [[Frank Ramsey]] <ref> Frank Ramsey “A Mathematical Theory of Saving”  Economic Journal Vol. 38 1928</ref>.  There is a note on the “Ramsey equation”, and the estimation of the associated elasticity measure, on the tutorials subpage.).  A community’s discount rate, taking  account of rising consumption, is termed its “social time preference rate”.


Related uses of the term “discount rate” include its application to a variety of interest rates, including the rate charged for loans made to a country’s banks by its central  bank <ref> See the article on [[financial economics]]</ref>, the rates of return that are used as investment criteria by companies <ref> See the article on [[business economics]]</ref>, and by government agencies <ref> See the article on [[cost/benefit analysis]]</ref>.
Related uses of the term “discount rate” include its application to a variety of interest rates, including the rate charged for loans made to a country’s banks by its central  bank <ref> See the article on [[financial economics]]</ref>, and the rates of return that are used as investment criteria by companies <ref> See the article on [[business economics]]</ref>  and by government agencies <ref> See the article on [[cost/benefit analysis]]</ref>.


==Financial implications==
==Financial implications==

Revision as of 05:03, 24 August 2008

This article is developing and not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Tutorials [?]
 
This editable Main Article is under development and subject to a disclaimer.

Definition

The concept of discounting arises from the behavioural observation that people prefer immediate satisfaction to deferred satisfaction. Thus the term “discount rate” refers to the compensation in terms of increased utility that a person requires as inducement to defer consumption (usually as a percentage per annum). The discount rate that a person experiences assuming no expectation of changing circumstances, is sometimes termed his “pure time preference rate” - to distinguish it from the inducement that he would require if he expected his consumption to increase. In that case, he would take account of the fact that, as his total consumption increased, he would experience a reduction in the marginal utility of any further increase [1]. The proportionate further compensation that a person requires to take account of its diminishing marginal utility is referred to as that person’s “elasticity of the marginal utility of consumption”. (The derivation of that concept is attributed to a 1928 paper by the economist Frank Ramsey [2]. There is a note on the “Ramsey equation”, and the estimation of the associated elasticity measure, on the tutorials subpage.). A community’s discount rate, taking account of rising consumption, is termed its “social time preference rate”.

Related uses of the term “discount rate” include its application to a variety of interest rates, including the rate charged for loans made to a country’s banks by its central bank [3], and the rates of return that are used as investment criteria by companies [4] and by government agencies [5].

Financial implications

"Time is money". Financial theory has tried to implement the fact that one cash flow received in the future is worth less than the same cash flow received today (i.e. one dollar in one year vs. one dollar received today). Any investor preferring to receive a cash flow sooner rather than later can put his money in a riskless saving account. The general formula for the discounting of a cash flow is given by:

where is the Net Present Value, is the Future value (i.e. of a cash flow) received at time and is the discount rate.

Rearranging this equation we have that:


The discount rate is the interest rate that links a future cash flow received a time to the same cash flow received now, at . It takes into account the length of the time period (the longer time it is, the higher it should be) and the risk related to the cash flow (the more uncertain it is, the higher the discount rate is).


Assume I have $80, and I buy a government bond that pays me $100 in a year's time. The discount rate represents the discount on the future cash flow:

Economic Policy

One of the major issues in economics is what is an appropriate discount rate to use under various circumstances. For example, in assessing the impact of very long-term phenomena such as climate change, use of any discount rate much more than 1% per annum renders long-term damage (occurring in, say, 200 years time) of negligible importance now.

Conversely, governments often take a short-term view of things, effectively applying discount rates of perhaps 20% p.a. or higher, on the grounds that anything they do or fail to do which has detrimental effects in (say) 10 or more years' time won't prevent their re-election sooner than that.

In practice, discount rates such as 2%, 3%, 5% and 10% are widely used in economics. However there is little consensus on what value is appropriate in any given circumstance, and it often makes a significant difference.

Context Specific Uses

Credit cards
For more information, see: Merchant account.
The discount rate is a percentage of the dollar amount of the transaction that a merchant is charged for each credit card transaction.
Monetary Policy
The discount rate is the rate that an eligible depository institution (such as a bank) is charged to borrow short term funds directly from the central bank through the discount window. This is also known as the base rate, repo rate and/or primary rate, as a profit-making bank will need to charge rates higher than this to its customers.

External links

References

  1. See the article on supply and demand
  2. Frank Ramsey “A Mathematical Theory of Saving” Economic Journal Vol. 38 1928
  3. See the article on financial economics
  4. See the article on business economics
  5. See the article on cost/benefit analysis